What happens when increasingly, not all that counts is being counted.
The desire to measure all things is deeply ingrained in
human beings. It is an essential mechanism for comparison, which supports our
earliest cognitive development. In time, we learn to put specific yardsticks to
these such as rulers, scales and thermometers.
The most important measurement of all, and one which
drives most of us and completely dominates our lives is that which defines
value. It is that measure that is vital to all of transaction, in turn
supporting the social construct we call economics. Yet, for all of its paramount
importance, it is the one measure that is severely flawed.
The first flaw lies in the dual nature of value. It has
both an objective and subjective nature; a tangible and intangible; a
quantitative and qualitative. And while we rely on the quantitative to guide
and shape economic forces, policies, supply, demand, trade, measures and
regulations; it is the qualitative, the immeasurable, that in the end trumps
the measureable and is far more important to individual experiences. The
quantitative measurement we call price, is merely a reflection of a transactional
moment. The way that object or service behaves, is the ultimate determinant of
value.
The second major flaw is in the quantitative measure of
value itself – the price. Text book economists may argue that price is the
balancing fulcrum between supply and demand, and therefore represents true
value. But there is no market that is truly free or pure. The only virtue in the
price argument is that for all of their flaws, market informed prices are still
far better than regulated or fixed prices. That argument becomes increasingly
difficult to defend when markets are contaminated by inappropriate behaviour
and when speculative derivatives distort prices. Unrestricted markets certainly
cannot claim to reflect true value accurately.
In addition, the unit of measure, money, or specifically
the currency, is flawed. For one thing inflation ensures that measured values can
change irrespective of supply and demand. Effectively it means that unlike a
meter which is a unit of length of absolute constant accuracy, the unit in
which we measure value is not constant. In addition, the relative value of one
currency to another is even more volatile and can change dramatically on all
kinds of whims, as we in South Africa well know. On top of that globally we
have delinked money from intrinsic value such as gold or to tangible value in
the production of goods and services. Money is now linked to debt creation,
which has expanded unprecedentedly and threatens money’s future as a means of
exchange and unit of measure.
We have nonchalantly learned to live with these
shortcomings in our daily lives, routinely adjusting to these forces and mostly
oblivious to the cracks they may be creating in our economic environment. That may be well and good, but when these
contaminants filter through and form the base of macro-measurements that have a
profound influence and give direction to far reaching policies and decision
making, then they surely must create a vicious circle that entrench and widen
those cracks. We tolerate these things simply because we know nothing else, and
despite all the advances in information gathering and processing, there is no
serious move towards doing things differently.
The most important of the macro metrics are GDP and
inflation. The first measures the value of goods and services produced in a
country in a given year, and the second the movement of consumer prices. Apart
from resting on the above flawed measure of value, they suffer from severe
defects in the way they are compiled and often interpreted. That’s when the
quantitative can also distort the qualitative, changing daily routines and
important features of social life.
The inflation measure is
always a bone of contention. (See previous
article here.) As an extrapolation to an average, it has as much chance of
fitting the price experience of the “average” person as winning the lotto. Yet
it is routinely used to determine important decisions such as wages and
interest rates. One aspect that is often missed is that it excludes important household
costs such as income tax, which have a profound impact on the middle and upper
income classes. Other taxes, such as VAT, customs duties and the fuel levy push
up inflation but have nothing to do with supply and demand. Increasingly too,
the practice of shrinkflation
is distorting the picture.
GDP (yes, here
we go again!) creates an even deeper anomaly. It has a bigger influence in
determining decisions that affect our daily lives than any other macro
measurement. Interpretations of underlying forces can differ widely with
forecasts of economic growth this year varying from +1.2% to -0.9%. The GDP
measurement stands on three very wobbly legs: the impurity of the unit of
measure outlined earlier; the potential for various interpretations; and the
third, probably the most important -- its constituents: what does it count and
what does it leave out.
The omission of qualitative values was lamented decades
ago by American Senator Bobby Kennedy in his famous conclusion that it
“measures everything, except that which is worthwhile.” It’s a lament that has
been carried forward for decades, the
latest from Nobel Laureate, Michael Spence.
But even selection of the tangible, or measurable, is sometimes
arbitrary to say the least: like Nigeria’s huge leap in GDP after a reshuffling
of the GDP constituents and Egypt
overtaking South Africa in size based on an exchange rate. Or the U.K.’s including
proceeds from sex and drugs to boost its GDP and overtake France in
economic size.
And now a new dimension has been added to the debate.
What happens when something of value keeps that value but loses its price? In
effect, it moves from the quantitative to the qualitative. When something does
not have a price, it can no longer be measured. And if it was included in the
metrics before, it simply falls away, losing its impact on both GDP and CPI,
amongst others. One could argue that it partly moves from product to
advertising and is simply recovered differently. But will it have the same impact?
It is an intriguing question raised by independent
economist, Cees Bruggemans, in a recent
edition of Economic Insights. Sir Charles Bean, Professor at the
London School of Economics, went further in a
recent WEF publication to suggest a
rethink of how we measure economic activity. Bean points out that in a number
of areas, technology has disrupted pricing, processes, and even the way
companies operate. These include music, entertainment, communication, internet
services, information gathering, banking, travel agents and insurance agents.
The relevance and
reliability of some of our key measurements is increasingly becoming a more
critical issue. I’m waiting for the day when Pravin Gordhan has one of his
media briefings and emphasises the importance of increasing GDP, and when some
junior maverick reporter questions the relevance and reliability of the measurement
itself. His answer is predictable: “What else is there?”
That, indeed is
the challenge.
No comments:
Post a Comment