Can South Africa create a fresh economic approach to growth and inclusivity?
Part
of the enthusiasm of a “new dawn” in South Africa is the belief that a closer
partnership can be established between labour, capital and state. It has a firm
Ramaphosa stamp to it and is key to the President’s desire to galvanise the
nation on a different business friendly path of cohesion, inclusivity and
growth.
In
this he has put renewed emphasis on the CEO initiative and the National
Economic Development and Labour Council (NEDLAC) as “unique institutions” in
bringing the three economic estates together and that are envied by many other
nations. Sceptics could argue that most nations do not need them and have long
since evolved beyond 19th century ideological divisions captured in
theories of “capitalism” and “socialism” that still mesmerise many in this
country. (See article: An age of economic soul searching here.)
Only
a political or organisational theorist could come up with a term such as
“stakeholder capitalism”. It’s counter-intuitive to the very definition of
capitalism and borders on being an oxymoron. The classic definition of capitalism
assumes the supremacy of ownership over “stakeholders”. Perhaps it is time to
move beyond the debilitating semantics of capitalism and socialism. There are
so many permutations of both in different settings that neither exists in its
pure form. Yet the words themselves ignite knee jerk responses based on stubbornly
nurtured prejudices.
Associative
meaning has a subtle way of creating unshakeable intuitive prejudice – to the
extent that many baby names are banned in some countries
with some nations even having a pre-approved list. Have the words “capitalism
and socialism” not reached that point? And perhaps with them other concoctions
such as “communism”, “neo-liberalism”, “social capitalism” and “stakeholder
capitalism”. There is, of course, much value in the inclusive stakeholder
approach, but to achieve that, one simply has to let go of much of what is
conventional capitalism – including the purpose of business and the accounting
formats -- in favour of a common purpose;
common fate approach.
It
will also need a clearer distinction between capitalism and other concepts such
as “free enterprise”, “free markets” and even notions such as innovation,
entrepreneurship, and prosperity. Without that distinction, those laudable,
more palatable and easily defended concepts become tainted with many negative
connotations associated with the name of capitalism. It is said to be in a
crisis. Its face has been called “unacceptable”.
It’s been slandered as “ugly”. It’s even been demeaned as having
no face at all.
It solicits ill-informed responses from populist leaders that inflame without
enlightening: much heat without light. Included in its defence, and entrenched
by the word itself, are questionable assumptions about what accounts for its
success.
The
first is that human beings are singularly driven by their immediate material
self-interest and profit. That is a silly generalisation. Human beings are far
more complex than that. Free enterprise supports a different understanding, as
pronounced by Adam Smith (See here). Without a good
measure of benevolent behaviour we attract the very nemesis of free enterprise:
more rules, regulations, laws, government controls and even coerced empathy in
the form of a system mildly called socialism. Which prompts me to burst another
assumption bubble: because homo
economicus is a social being rather than simply a functional entity in one
or other construct, it does not support the radical socialist argument of ownership
by all – or ownership by none.
Interestingly,
while capitalism is blindly married to the material self-gain driver, free
enterprise does not concern itself with motive: as long as it is led by the
fundamental rule that wealth is the result of creating something of tangible value
for others or being useful to fellow human beings. In that it has a fundamental
benevolent underpinning. Free enterprise is remarkably resilient and
accommodating, and does not attract or even need the fanatical posturing that
advocates either for or against often adopt in an understandable blind prejudice.
Even in its aversion to socialism and the latter’s implication of bigger
government at the expense of private initiative, it can accommodate
permutations that fly in the teeth of many arguments.
Capitalism
vehemently champions my old pet objection: the profit motive and profit
maximisation as the ultimate driver of success and prosperity. I do not intend repeating my
challenge
to this claim as simply being false. What is worth repeating is the outrageous
and demeaning assumption it makes about the motives of entrepreneurial giants
who have made a marked and lasting impact on humankind. The social miracle of
free enterprise is its ability to forge cohesion and a sense of common purpose
between stakeholders. That obviously implies not trying to rank one above the
other, and certainly not encouraging the exploitation by one of the other.
That
is implied in the name “capitalism” itself. It assumes capital supremacy in all
things, and the pursuit of its formation and growth is a precursor to all kinds
of wonderful stuff. Free enterprise accommodates, indeed proposes, a different
view: that enterprise leads and capital follows. Capital is indeed a critical
enabler. But so are skills and labour, and government services and
infra-structure. But the ultimate enabler is demand.
The
results of a narrow and exclusive view on the role of capital formation have
been devastating. We have not seen significant capital formation in organic
growth through multiples of mom-and- pop ventures, small and medium enterprise
growth, and growing middle classes; but in mergers, acquisitions, financial
services, and financial or property assets. Control of capital, not necessarily
ownership, has increasingly been concentrated in the hands of the few, who in
turn, some have argued, have “captured” many free enterprise activities, parts
of government, and the most invidious of all: banking and money creation.
The
term “monopoly capital” may have no logical basis, but it’s simply a reflection
of trying to find, or even create a demon that “will be confronted” by voting
for some populist megalomaniac. The concentration of control over the means of
production, either by government or a few plutocrats is the antithesis of free
enterprise. The term itself is a P.R nightmare. Even in its origins it was demonised by novelist Thackeray to
represent an exploitive landlord. It never featured in Adam Smith’s writings,
but was repeatedly used by Karl Marx. So it was coined by its enemies.
I
have no doubt opened the gates of wrath of many readers. And that is the
essence of the problem, emotive responses linked to a name. You will unlikely
find these observations in economic textbooks. The reason is simple: for the
most part I have been dealing with perceptions, which most textbooks and
academics ignore. At the same time they fail to recognise a fundamental truth:
that perceptions create reality.
The
one thing that globalisation has shown is that there is no one-size-fits all best
economic system. All countries have their own uniqueness that often defy
ideological prescriptions. Each has to evolve in its own way.
If
we want to create something fresh, let’s not muddy it with dogmatic
assumptions.
No comments:
Post a Comment