Was the great recession a bigger game changer than we realise?
In women’s month, on a cold Sunday night in the
farm-workers’ compound, cheap wine-fuelled joviality again turns to discord. A
stone is thrown in drunken fury. A skull is crushed. A young women dies. A
young man ends in jail. One life is ended, another destroyed. Neighbours and
co-workers become sworn enemies. Tranquillity in the small community is shattered.
A few more decibels are added to the clamour about gender
violence. Another line is written in the tome of hazy hopelessness that is the
life of a very large part of a young generation. And just as many in the final
generation, those whose formative years were marked by much post-war deprivation
but large promise of “never again”, reflect sadly on what has been done to that
promise. It’s a global story. The content may differ, but the context is the
same: a fractured, disconnected, economically malfunctioning world. Is the new normal, as Dutch economist, Servaas
Storm says: “radical inequality, suffocating debt, job uncertainty, secular
stagnation and a vanishing middle-class”? Theories abound. Purists argue that
their elixirs were never purely administered. Solutions exceed the problems
themselves, but none has proved to be a lasting absolute truth. Some hope that
the current few green shoots in the desert will still the dissent.
We are not too afraid of “unchartered waters”, drawing
some comfort from history that we have been in unfamiliar places before, and
somehow emerged with new approaches and discoveries. This time is no different.
But perhaps it is in the scale and depth of questioning all assumptions about
economics and about ourselves as a species. The view increasingly being seen is
through an evolutionary rather than the traditional reactive quantitative lens –
do we evolve or construct on statistical models? This lens is being captured in
research directions and discoveries within evolutionary economics and
complexity economics, and driven by a number of institutions and scholars.
Eric
Beinhocker Executive Director of the Institute for New Economic Thinking at
Oxford University, believes the financial crisis of 2008 and the momentous
global political shifts last year, have heralded a collapse of major
economic-political ideologies that have dominated the 20th century. Older
economies in particular are searching for a completely new paradigm that can
show a better way for all. Such as the OECD’s NAEC (New approaches to Economic Challenges)
which says: “We need a full re-vamp of our analytical frameworks and the
assumptions that we make, to better capture the reality. Economic models that
rely only on inputs such as GDP, income per capita, trade flows, resource
allocation, productivity, representative agents, and so on can tell a part of
the story, but they fail to capture the distributional consequences of the
policies we make, and do not address the fact that the growth process has
only benefited a few.”
It will be a mistake to see these shifts in economic
introspection in an ideological context, and brand them as “socialist” or
“left”. Indeed our sometimes powerfully drawing biases are the biggest barriers
to discovery. According to Beinhocker, it’s time for new economic thinking
based on the best science available, not Ideology. “It should be highly interdisciplinary”
he says, “involving not only economists, but psychologists, anthropologists,
sociologists, historians, physicists, biologists, mathematicians, computer
scientists, and others across the social and physical sciences”. He notes
that over the past several decades a number of Nobel prizes have been given
to researchers working in what today might be called the new economics
tradition.
Beinhocker reflects a common thread followed by economic
evolutionary advocates in developing a view of the economy as an evolutionary
system of cooperative problem solving. Prosperity is seen as “solutions to
human problems” and cooperation is the key to solving more and more complex
problems thus increasing prosperity.
“Economics has painted itself as a detached amoral
science, but humans are moral creatures. We must bring morality back into the
centre of economics in order for people to relate to and trust it,” he says.
Oxford and Cambridge Research Associate, Kate Raworth in
following that thought in her latest book, suggests
dumping GDP as the holy grail and setting a “far more ambitious and global
economic goal: meeting the needs of all within the means of the
planet”. She then explores a seven
step approach to achieving that.
In this article, David
Wilson, renowned biologist and anthropologist at Binghamton University,
suggests not only that Adam Smith’s invisible hand is dead, and always fails,
but that the metaphor itself has caused much harm. “We are different from other
primate species,” he argues, “because we are so cooperative. Why are we so
cooperative? Because it is so easy to regulate each other’s behaviour in small
face-to-face groups.” Wilson’s brave challenge of the “invisible hand” has
another context: Smith’s assumption of high moral standards in humanity, which precluded
seeing “the hand” as an instrument of pure self-gain and
unbridled selfishness.
“Moral systems
evolve in societies because they enhance group cohesion and survival.
Implications of
evolutionary thinking for economics and the social sciences have only partially
been explored.” (Geoffrey
M. Hodgson, research professor at Hertfordshire Business School,
University of Hertfordshire, England.)
One of the more
telling indictments of orthodox economic models is from complexity economics of
which Steve Keen, Kingston University economist and author
of Debunking
Economics is a leading advocate. He believes economists have to embrace
complexity to avoid disaster and the fact that they don’t, explains why most
were caught flatfooted by the speed, depth and length of the great recession.
“Macroeconomic models are painstakingly derived from microeconomic foundations,
in the false belief that it is legitimate to scale the individual up to the
level of society.” Using his own simulations, Keen shows a number of cases (see essay here) where generally accepted assumptions at a
micro level, including important ones such as price and demand, simply don’t
hold true at a macro level.
It is extremely
difficult to do this important subject justice in a broad sweep such as I have
made here. Essays and articles on the website evonomics.com
bear testimony to the
weight, depth and breadth of a perspective that is perhaps not new but compelling,
profound and refreshing in today’s context. It does offer a framework of
thought for South Africa’s own Radical Economic transformation, but with a huge
caveat – the need for a trustworthy government. I have frequently argued that
radical government transformation is an absolute prerequisite for RET. (See article here.)
What remains
unchallenged and perhaps gains significance is that economics itself is built
on the enduring principle of adding value to each other’s lives. This should
put business and companies at the core of any economic construct seen through
any lens.
From a
relationship point of view, they are after all, and irrespective of motive, an
inclusive collective of people serving people.
No comments:
Post a Comment